A Core of Practical Macroeconomics

A Core of Practical Macroeconomics
JOHN B. TAYLOR

The American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred and Fourth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, (May, 1997), pp. 233-235

Macroeconomics-the part of economics that focuses on economic growth and economic fluctuations-has always been an area of great controversy and debate. Over 150 years ago David Ricardo argued with Thomas Malthus over the importance of supply versus demand in growth and fluctuations, much as real-business-cycle economists have argued with monetarists and Keynesians in recent years. The Keynesian revolution of the 1930's and the rational-expectations revolution of the 1970's, both questioning macroeconomic ideas of the time, were two of the most contentious episodes in the history of economic thought. Some view recent macroeconomic debates as so intense that they see macroeconomics as nothing more than competing camps of economists with no common set of core principles.

I welcomed the opportunity to appear on this panel because, in my view, there is a set of key principles -a core -of macroeconomics about which there is wide agreement. This core is the outgrowth of the many recent debates about Keynesianism, monetarism, neoclassical growth theory, real-business-cycle theory, and rational expectations. The core is practical in the sense that it is having a beneficial effect on macroeconomic policy, especially monetary policy, and has resulted in improvements in policy in the last 15 years. In fact, new econometric models recently put in operation at the Fed largely reflect this core. This core is increasingly evident in undergraduate economics texts, and it also appears in graduate training, though in most Ph.D. programs there is much more emphasis on the newer and more controversial parts.
Although there are different ways to characterize this core, I would list five key principles. I would start with the most basic and least controversial principle, focusing on longterm economic growth and the supply side of the economy. Over the long term, labor productivity growth depends on the growth of capital per hour of work and on the growth of technology or, more precisely, on movements along as well as shifts of a production function, as Robert Solow pointed out many years ago. If one adds to this labor productivity growth an estimate of labor-force growth, one gets an estimate of the long-run growth rate of real GDP, or what is typically referred to as potential GDP growth. This principle, the essence of neoclassical growth theory, provides a way to estimate and discuss the sources of long-term economic growth within the organizing structure of the growth accounting formula. Key policy questions to address within this framework, of course, are why potencial GDP growth has declined and what can be done to raise it again.
Is this first principle practical? Yes. Public policy economists at the Fed and the Congressional Budget Office and private industry economists regularly use this approach to get estimates of potential GDP growth. Most now estimate this growth to be about 2-2.5 percent per year. Of course there are debates about how to apply this principle: Are there diminishing returns to information capital? How much would fundamental tax reform raise the capital-labor ratio? How much does a reducción in marginal tax rates increase labor supply? But these are more quantitative issues, concerning the size of elasticities, rather than matters of principle.

A second key macroeconomic principle is that there is no long-term trade-off between the rate of inflation and the rate of unemployment; a corollary is that a shift by the central bank to a higher rate of money growth will simply result in more inflation in the long run, with the unemployment rate remaining unchanged. Although controversial at one time, this does not appear to be controversial anymore; empirical and theoretical research provides strong support. In the 1960's inflación was low, and unemployment was between 5 percent and 6 percent; in the 1970's inflation was high, and unemployment was no lower; and in the 1990's inflation is low again, and unemployment has not increased. There are two qualifications to this principle: (i) inter-national evidence from different countries in-dicates that high rates of inflation appear to reduce the growth of potential GDP, and (ii) very low rates of inflation, in particular defla-tion, may be an impediment to the smooth op-eration of markets, both because of a lower bound on the nominal interest rate and because of the stickiness of prices and wages.

This second principle has already had a majorpractical impact on policy. It implies that central banks should pick a long-run target range for inflation and stick with it. Many central banks around the world are doing just that either explicitly as with New Zealand and the United Kingdom or implicitly as with the United States and Germany. A third principle is that there is a short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment. In my view this trade-off is best described as one between the variability of inflation and the variability of unemployment. There is still debate about the reason for this trade-off. One rationale is the sticky-price/staggered-wage theory which I favor; but there is also the information-based theory put forth by Robert Lucas. There is also an Chongoing debate about the monetary transmission mechanism: does monetary policy work through a money channel, a credit channel, or through a financial price channel (interest rates and exchange rates)?

Despite these debatable underpinnings, the existence of a short-run trade-off has practical implications for policy: monetary policy should keep the growth of aggregate demand stable in order to prevent fluctuations in real output and inflation. In fact, the improvements of monetary policy during the last 15 years have led to much more stable macroeconomic conditions. The United States is now experiencing, back-to-back, the two longest peacetime expansions ( 1982-1990 and 1991-1997) in U.S. history, separated by one of the mildest recessions in U.S. history (1990- 1991 ). A greater stability of monetary policy, including explicit discussions and actions consistent with the goal of keeping inflation low, is largely responsible for this record-brea King macroeconomic stability. Every recession since the 1950's has been preceded by a run up of inflation; by keeping inflation from ricino in the first place, the chances of such recessions are diminished. A fourth macroeconomic principle is that peoples' expectations are highly responsive to policy, and thus, expectations matter for assessing the impact of monetary and fiscal policy. The most feasible empirical way to model this response or endogeneity of expectations is the rational-expectations approach, though modifications to take account of differing degrees of credibility are necessary. By introducing rational expectations into fully estimated econometric models and then simulating the models for different policies, the response of expectations to changes in policy can be reasonably approximated (see Taylor, 1993).

Is this fourth principle having an impact on practice? Yes. For example, macroeconomic models with rational expectations now in use at the Fed are able to estimate the effects on interest rates of a multiyear plan to reduce the future budget deficit (see Flint Brayton et al., 1997). These models can help guide monetary decisions about interest rates when a plan for budget deficit reduction (like that in 1990 or 1993 in the United States) is being considered. Additional evidence for the practical relevance of this principle is the great emphasis placed on credibility by central banks today. According to rational-expectations models, there are advantages to credibility in both monetary policy and fiscal policy. For example, a disinflation will have lower short-run costs if policy is credible. Similarly, a plan to reduce the budget deficit will have a smaller short-run contractionary effect if it is credible. A fifth principle is that when evaluating monetary and fiscal policy one should not think in terms of a one-time isolated change in the instruments of policy, but rather as a series of changes linked by a systematic process or a policy rule. This fifth principle follows from many of the other principles. It is very evidente in academic policy-evaluation research during the past 15 years, where virtually all formal policy evaluation has been done in terms ofpolicy rules. To be sure there is debate about the form of the policy rules: Should the interest rate or the money supply be the instruments in the rule? Should the instrument react to the exchange rate or solely to inflation and real output? How large should the reaction of pol-icy be to inflation? Is the rule a guideline or should it be legislated and used to add ac-countability to policy-making?

Recently there has been increased practicali nterest in policy rules. For example, in recent speeches, Federal Reserve Board Governors Laurence Meyer ( 1996) and Janet Yellen (1996) have described in detail how policy rules can be helpful in the formulation of monetary policy. Speaking about her practical experience on the Federal Reserve Board, Yellen states (p. 10) that "... rules provide a simple but useful benchmark to assess the setting of monetary policy in a very complex and uncertain economic environment." The Federal Reserve Board staff now regularly does stochastic simulation of alternative policy rules. And many private-sector business economists have noted the similarity between the actions of the Fed and many other central banks to the outcomes implied by certain policy rules.

In conclusion, let me emphasize that this characterization of a core of practical macroeconomics is not meant to imply that everything is settled in macroeconomics. On the contrary, there are still great debates going on over the size of elasticities, the role of credit in the monetary transmission mechanism, the empirical relevance of "endogenous" growth models, whether staggered price-setting models with rational expectations fit satisfactorily the dynamic correlations that characterize the process of inflation in the United States, and many other issues. One question that will continue to be debated for many years is how much formal optimization is appropriate in order to provide a solid underpinning to macroeconomics. Many of the macroeconomic models I referred to in this discussion are economy-wide generalequilibrium models which have sticky-price equations as part of their structure; but there is still much more work to be done to fully establish the optimization basis for many of these sticky price structures. The current effort to incorporate money and sticky prices into real-business-cycle models will hasten the day when models with a more fully articulated optimization structure are used in practice for policy-making. I believe that this work will add much to economists' understanding of the macroeconomic principles summarized in this discussion, but in the meantime, there is a solid core of macroeconomic principles which is useful in practical policy work and which has already improved macroeconomic policymaking in the United States and other countries.

REFERENCES

Brayton, Flint; Levin, Andrew; Tryon, Ralph andWilliams, John. "The Evolution of MacroModels at the Federal Reserve Board." Carnegie Rochester Series on Public Policy, 1997 (forthcoming).

Meyer, Laurence H. "Monetary Policy Objectives and Strategy." Remarks before the National Association of Business Economists 38th Annual Meeting, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC, 8 September 1996.

Taylor, John B. Macroeconomic policy in a world economy. New York: Norton, 1993.


Yellen, Janet. "Monetary Policy: Goals and Strategy." Remarks before the National Association of Business Economists, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC, 13 March 1996.

La economia mexicana de dos decadas...

A raiz del "regreso" de CSG, Macario Schettino comenta en su blog que tanto Zedillo como Salinas tienen razon en echarse la culpa de la crisis (vinculo al blog de Macario S. en la columna de la derecha). Uno por "dejar a la economia muy fragil", el otro por el famoso error de diciembre. Salida salomonica diriamos, como la de las mamas que castigan a los dos hermanos que insisten, cada uno, que "el empezo"... Como buen analista, Schettino fundamenta su opinion, que comentamos aqui en rojo: (Nota la figura de abajo la importamos del blog de MS)

Macario Schettino. Errores y regreso (extracto). Entrada del 12 de mayo de 2008 de su blog Economia 2.0.

"En pocas palabras: Salinas tiene razón al acusar a Zedillo de haber devaluado muy mal. Pero Zedillo tiene razón en culpar a Salinas de haber dejado la economía en una situación muy vulnerable. [Me parece que Schettino no ha leido el otro libro de CSG, en el que detalla el asunto de el error de diciembre. Segun la tesis de CSG -por cierto, sin replica puntual en 8 anios- el dejaba "un problema en balanza de pagos" que EZPL transformo en "una crisis de balanza de pagos". Los documentos que fundamentan esa tesis estan en el otro libro de CSG] Para ejemplificar, permítame utilizar una gráfica. En ella aparece el déficit en la cuenta corriente de nuestro país. La cuenta corriente mide todas las transacciones de bienes y servicios de un país con el resto del mundo. Cuando un país tiene un déficit en cuenta corriente, significa que el resto del mundo lo está financiando. Cuando ese déficit es grande, el resto del mundo deja de financiarlo, y no queda más remedio que devaluar. En nuestro caso, “grande” significa 5% del PIB. Cada vez que hemos tenido un déficit de ese tamaño, el resto del mundo ha dejado de financiarnos, y hemos tenido que devaluar. Como puede ver en la gráfica, esto ocurrió en 1976, en 1982 y en 1994… [Me parece que es una conclusion apresurada. No se trata de decir que no se pueden establecer relaciones causales como Schettino hace ahora, sino que me parece que en este caso la conclusion olvida algo crucial: el regimen cambiario. Si la devaluacion ocurre cuando el deficit alcanza 5 puntos me parece, en principio, casualidad antes que causalidad. Eso depende del regimen cambiario, que en ese entonces era fijo -en los ochenta- y con bandas moviles -o semifijo, si se permite el abuso del lenguaje, en los noventa con CSG-. Para aceptar la hipotesis se requiere informacion sobre el regimen cambiario, que es precisamente la que hay que ver cuando de devaluaciones se habla. CSG hace precisamente eso, lo que es normal en tanto analisis economico, y parece que cuando la historia se presenta viendo las reservas internacionales resulta mas convincente. Esto no quita que hay relaciones causales obvias entre las reservas internacionales y el deficit en cuenta corriente cuando hay tipo de cambio fijo, o incluso cuando el regimen es de flotacion sucia. El asunto es que ver nada mas al deficit olvida mirar el importante paso intermedio de las reservas. Asi, en principio, con reservas internacionales suficientes, un deficit del 5%, o del 10%, es financiable, por lo que la frase causal "deficit del 5%=devalacion" pierde validez. Si al analisis le metemos el asunto de la cuenta de capital, entonces un deficit del 10%, por ejemplo, se puede asociar analiticamente con un equilibrio de balanza de pagos, toda vez que la cuenta de capital tenga un superavit de magnitud comparable, dejando las reservas intactas. Esa fue, entre otras, la apuesta de la politica heterodoxa de CSG]

Se puede argumentar que no necesariamente un déficit tan grande lleva a una devaluación, poniendo como ejemplo a otros países [la "no-necesidad" no es nada mas por casos, sino analitica, como veiamos arriba] . Ciertamente, para cada país el nivel de déficit que lleva a que el resto del mundo deje de financiar es diferente, pero la evidencia de que en nuestro caso este nivel es 5% del PIB parece bastante fuerte. Es decir que Carlos Salinas sostuvo, durante la segunda mitad de su sexenio, un nivel muy peligroso, que sólo podía mantener con su acostumbrada “fuga hacia adelante”. Pero en algún momento eso podía fallar. Y falló cuando, efectivamente, un equipo menos capaz tomó las riendas.

Como puede usted ver, ni Salinas ni Zedillo son inocentes en esta crisis que envió a millones a la pobreza, y que hizo que miles perdieran sus negocios, sus empleos o sus casas. Sin embargo, a mí me sigue pareciendo que en el fondo, hay más culpables: todos los que a fines de 1993 insistían en que Salinas era el mejor presidente de la historia y que un año después lo acusaron de ser el peor villano. Porque vivimos tres años al borde de la crisis, pero prácticamente nadie criticó al gobierno, ni cuidó sus decisiones. [Hipotesis politica no muy solida, a mi juicio. Si CSG tuvo tanta culpa de la crisis como EZPL, entonces los analistas politicos y economicos debieron ver que estaba pasando. Me parece que, despues de ver muchas opiniones, incluida la de CSG (y excluida la de EZPL, a quien no le conozco una sola replica a 8 anios de las primeras acusaciones de CSG), la historia que resenia el mismo CSG tiene mas fundamentos. Esa conclusion puede resultar "politicamente incorrecta" para los "politicamente correctos", incapaces de ir en contra de la psique colectiva. Pero si eso da el analisis razonado, pues eso da. Ahora, el analisis economico no es totalmente concluyente, ni sus conclusiones unicas y atemporales. Pero eso es lo que tenemos...]

Por cierto, reitero mi aviso de que sin reforma energética llegaremos a tener un déficit en cuenta corriente de ese tamaño, 5% del PIB, para fines de 2010. [Aviso ante el cual tomamos nota. Esto no necesariamente provoca devaluacion, como se lee entre lineas en la entrada de Schettino, pues primero estamos en flotacion (sucia, pero flotacion al fin), y segunda, las reservas internacionales estan en maximos historicos, lo mismo que la cuenta de capital, que tiene un dinamismo mucho mayor que en 1994]

¿Quién es más culpable: Salinas o Zedillo? ¿Qué tanto somos culpables los mexicanos por no cuidar de nosotros mismos? ¿Qué tanto seremos culpables de posponer decisiones en Pemex? ¿A quién culparemos ahora? [Preguntas, esas si, muy relevantes]

Ustedes dirán…